Friday, May 10, 2019
MicroL20 Essay Example | Topics and Well Written Essays - 1250 words
MicroL20 - Essay sheathb. An example of a good with a positive externality is occupied housing. Certainly, the individuals housed benefit from shelter, security, and an ability to rig out their lives and families in a way that would not likely be feasible if they were homeless. Owners enjoy rents (implicit if the belongings is owner-occupied) on the home. These are primarily close benefits. Occupied housing tends to be better maintained, improving neighborhood property values) over the long term and neighborhoods with higher occupancy rates tend to have lower umbrage rates. Both of these are primarily customary benefits. An example of a good with a negative externality is a car with an extremely loud stereo system. While the audiophile-owner may enjoy the experience (a private benefit), those who are forced to experience the sound against their allow for are faced with a nuisance (a public cost). 2. Monopolies. a. If bar sensationt charges $15, then he handles a meal for a follow profit of $10. If he charges $8, hell betray two meals for a total profit of $6. If he charges $7, hell sell trio meals at a total profit of $6. Its in Barts best interest to charge $15.00 and sell a single meal. The producer unneeded in this case is $10 and there is no consumer surplus. b. Without advanced knowledge of who would be willing to even up which monetary value, it would be difficult for him to equipment casualty discriminate, but there are both(prenominal) strategies he susceptibility pursue. peerless is to institute haggling. If every deed is negotiated, it is possible that those willing to pay a higher price might be persuaded to part with more cash for the same meal than a less well-funded customer (though this increases transaction costs). It might also be possible for Bart to create categories of customers, through some sort of discounting mechanism, which would realise it more likely that those willing to pay more would spend more. He might create three cosmetically different, though essentially similar, meals (though this pushes the boundaries of the premise, since the meals would no longer be the same). Ideally, he would be able to sell three meals, one each for $15, $8 and $7. In reality, with imperfect information, hed likely not do this well. c. Bart would be able to sell three meals, one each for $15, $8 and $7. The producer surplus will be $15 and there will be no consumer surplus. d. If all three meals were purchased by one person, it would be difficult for Brad to price discriminate, except, perhaps, by the use of discount cards or some similar device that needed to be presented upon ordering or paying. Assuming he could not price discriminate and the consumers presented a united, three meals or nothing front, we would expect three meals sold at $7 each. e. If there were another restaurant in town, it would be much more difficult for Bart to price discriminate. He would need to depend on factors such as market fricti on, customer loyalty or location preference (i.e., Barts restaurant is easier to get to) or collusion with his competitor to maintain some peak of monopoly power if he wanted to continue to price discriminate. As the number of competitors increased the situation would increasingly resemble a perfect competition model and Bart would become a price taker. f. It would be very difficult to effectively price discriminate
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.